skip to main content


Title: Lower Bounds on Implementing Mediators in Asynchronous Systems with Rational and Malicious Agents
Abraham, Dolev, Geffner, and Halpern [ 1 ] proved that, in asynchronous systems, a (k, t)-robust equilibrium for n players and a trusted mediator can be implemented without the mediator as long as n > 4( k+t ), where an equilibrium is ( k, t )-robust if, roughly speaking, no coalition of t players can decrease the payoff of any of the other players, and no coalition of k players can increase their payoff by deviating. We prove that this bound is tight, in the sense that if n ≤ 4( k+t ) there exist ( k, t )-robust equilibria with a mediator that cannot be implemented by the players alone. Even though implementing ( k, t )-robust mediators seems closely related to implementing asynchronous multiparty ( k+t )-secure computation [ 6 ], to the best of our knowledge there is no known straightforward reduction from one problem to another. Nevertheless, we show that there is a non-trivial reduction from a slightly weaker notion of ( k+t )-secure computation, which we call ( k+t )-strict secure computation , to implementing ( k, t )-robust mediators. We prove the desired lower bound by showing that there are functions on n variables that cannot be ( k+t )-strictly securely computed if n ≤ 4( k+t ). This also provides a simple alternative proof for the well-known lower bound of 4 t +1 on asynchronous secure computation in the presence of up to t malicious agents [ 4 , 8 , 10 ].  more » « less
Award ID(s):
1703846
NSF-PAR ID:
10414134
Author(s) / Creator(s):
;
Date Published:
Journal Name:
Journal of the ACM
Volume:
70
Issue:
2
ISSN:
0004-5411
Page Range / eLocation ID:
1 to 21
Format(s):
Medium: X
Sponsoring Org:
National Science Foundation
More Like this
  1. Secure function computation has been thoroughly studied and optimized in the past decades. We extend techniques used for secure computation to simulate arbitrary protocols involving a mediator. The key feature of our notion of simulation is that it is bidirectional: not only does the simulation produce only outputs that could happen in the original protocol, but the simulation produces all such outputs. In asynchronous systems there are also new subtleties that arise because the scheduler can influence the output. Thus, these requirements cannot be achieved by the standard notion of secure computation. We provide a construction that is secure if n > 4t, where t is the number of malicious agents, which is provably the best possible. We also show that our construction is secure in the universal composability model and that it satisfies additional security properties even if 3t < n \le 4t. 
    more » « less
  2. A mediator can help non-cooperative agents obtain an equilibrium that may otherwise not be possible. We study the ability of players to obtain the same equilibrium without a mediator, using only cheap talk, that is, nonbinding pre-play communication. Previous work has considered this problem in a synchronous setting. Here we consider the effect of asynchrony on the problem, and provide upper bounds for implementing mediators. Considering asynchronous environments introduces new subtleties, including exactly what solution concept is most appropriate and determining what move is played if the cheap talk goes on forever. Different results are obtained depending on whether the move after such ``infinite play'' is under the control of the players or part of the description of the game. 
    more » « less
  3. We consider computational games, sequences of games G = (G1,G2,...) where, for all n, Gn has the same set of players. Computational games arise in electronic money systems such as Bitcoin, in cryptographic protocols, and in the study of generative adversarial networks in machine learning. Assuming that one-way functions exist, we prove that there is 2-player zero-sum computational game G such that, for all n, the size of the action space in Gn is polynomial in n and the utility function in Gn is computable in time polynomial in n, and yet there is no ε-Nash equilibrium if players are restricted to using strategies computable by polynomial-time Turing machines, where we use a notion of Nash equilibrium that is tailored to computational games. We also show that an ε-Nash equilibrium may not exist if players are constrained to perform at most T computational steps in each of the games in the sequence. On the other hand, we show that if players can use arbitrary Turing machines to compute their strategies, then every computational game has an ε-Nash equilibrium. These results may shed light on competitive settings where the availability of more running time or faster algorithms can lead to a “computational arms race”, precluding the existence of equilibrium. They also point to inherent limitations of concepts such as “best response” and Nash equilibrium in games with resource-bounded players. 
    more » « less
  4. Cussens, James ; Zhang, Kun (Ed.)
    We investigate the problem of combinatorial multi-armed bandits with stochastic submodular (in expectation) rewards and full-bandit feedback, where no extra information other than the reward of selected action at each time step $t$ is observed. We propose a simple algorithm, Explore-Then-Commit Greedy (ETCG) and prove that it achieves a $(1-1/e)$-regret upper bound of $\mathcal{O}(n^\frac{1}{3}k^\frac{4}{3}T^\frac{2}{3}\log(T)^\frac{1}{2})$ for a horizon $T$, number of base elements $n$, and cardinality constraint $k$. We also show in experiments with synthetic and real-world data that the ETCG empirically outperforms other full-bandit methods. 
    more » « less
  5. Etessami, Kousha ; Feige, Uriel ; Puppis, Gabriele (Ed.)
    We study the time complexity of the discrete k-center problem and related (exact) geometric set cover problems when k or the size of the cover is small. We obtain a plethora of new results: - We give the first subquadratic algorithm for rectilinear discrete 3-center in 2D, running in Õ(n^{3/2}) time. - We prove a lower bound of Ω(n^{4/3-δ}) for rectilinear discrete 3-center in 4D, for any constant δ > 0, under a standard hypothesis about triangle detection in sparse graphs. - Given n points and n weighted axis-aligned unit squares in 2D, we give the first subquadratic algorithm for finding a minimum-weight cover of the points by 3 unit squares, running in Õ(n^{8/5}) time. We also prove a lower bound of Ω(n^{3/2-δ}) for the same problem in 2D, under the well-known APSP Hypothesis. For arbitrary axis-aligned rectangles in 2D, our upper bound is Õ(n^{7/4}). - We prove a lower bound of Ω(n^{2-δ}) for Euclidean discrete 2-center in 13D, under the Hyperclique Hypothesis. This lower bound nearly matches the straightforward upper bound of Õ(n^ω), if the matrix multiplication exponent ω is equal to 2. - We similarly prove an Ω(n^{k-δ}) lower bound for Euclidean discrete k-center in O(k) dimensions for any constant k ≥ 3, under the Hyperclique Hypothesis. This lower bound again nearly matches known upper bounds if ω = 2. - We also prove an Ω(n^{2-δ}) lower bound for the problem of finding 2 boxes to cover the largest number of points, given n points and n boxes in 12D . This matches the straightforward near-quadratic upper bound. 
    more » « less